Abstract
Historical data indicate that the relationship between inflation and output does not align closely with the Philips curve's implications. Since the late 1980s, monetary policy has prioritized price stability as a key component of sustainable long-term economic growth. This emphasis reflects policymakers' assumption that output volatility poses less risk to long-term growth than inflation volatility, though this assumption lacks empirical support in the literature. To address this gap, this study investigates the impact of inflation and output volatility on economic growth by analyzing panel data from 1990 to 2020 across 68 countries. Fixed Effect Models are employed to account for country-specific, time-invariant factors that may influence the relationship between volatilities and growth. The findings reveal a significant negative impact of output volatility on economic growth, even when inflation volatility is accounted for, suggesting that policymakers should consider output volatility alongside price stability to support sustained economic growth.
Key Words
Inflation volatility, Output Volatility, Phillips Curve, Economic Growth
Introduction
Stabilization of the general price level along with minimizing fluctuations in output are the overarching objectives of monetary policy. Prioritization of these two objectives has implications for volatility of output and inflation rate that in turn have effects on economic growth in the long run. If more weight is put on price stability as compared to output stabilization in monetary policy decisions, then the inflation rate remains within the acceptable range but at the cost of volatile output. Similarly, putting more weight on output stabilization makes the inflation rate volatile. Which volatility hampers economic growth the most remains a question that needs to be answered through research. In the late 1980s, there was a shift in monetary policy focus from output growth to price stability. The main reason behind this policy regime shift was the theoretical belief that price stability would provide an enabling environment for economic growth in the long run. However, this argument ignores the effect of strict inflation targeting on output volatility, which may hamper growth momentum. So, the benefits of price stability in the long run are compromised if output is not stable in the short run.
At a more basic level, the issue can be highlighted in terms of social loss function. Every individual wants to maximize their utility which depends on consumption and leisure. At the aggregate level, this translates to maximizing the social welfare function or minimizing the social loss function, which has price level and output as its arguments. Practically, public policy aims at minimizing deviations in output and inflation rates from their respective targets or normal values. So minimum variance of both output and inflation rate is desirable for the smooth functioning of the economy. However, both variances cannot be minimized simultaneously; the minimization of one, through policy intervention, renders the other to be out of control. So, from the policy's perspective, there is a volatility trade-off or variance tradeoff between output and inflation rate.
Until the 1970s the volatility tradeoff between output and prices was not very famous, therefore, the debate was about the level tradeoff between these two variables. This latter tradeoff was summarized by a famous empirical relationship – the Philips curve. Later on, it was found that the Phillips curve relationship was flawed and there was no policy tradeoff between inflation and output or unemployment. Notwithstanding the failure of the Phillips curve to guide monetary policy, the volatility tradeoff still remains there in academic and policy debates. The issue is especially important for developing economies, which are at an early stage of development and are prone to external shocks that make their weak output base unstable. Developed economies have already grown and their prime concern is the sustainability of economic activity with full employment and a low inflation rate. Therefore, the shift of policy focus from output and employment to price stability put developing economies at risk of being permanently in a low-growth trap. This is because they are unable to stabilize output due to inflation targeting; this short-term volatility in output hampers long-run growth momentum.
Literature Review
There is abundant literature available in this area, but it lacks one important aspect. This literature can be categorized into three groups with regard to the objectives of the studies. The first of these three groups consists of studies that look at the relationship between inflation and growth. The main conclusion drawn from these studies is that there is a negative relationship between inflation and growth (Friedman, 1977; Fisher, 1993; Barro, 1996; Zhang et al., 2023). The second group of studies focuses on the relationship between inflation volatility and economic growth. Barro (1995), Motley (1994), Judson (1999), and Guo Lim (2024) estimate the relationship between inflation volatility and economic growth. For the analysis, some of them took time series data while others used panel data, but they reached a similar conclusion that the coefficient of inflation volatility is negative and significant in the regression of economic growth. The third group consists of studies that estimate the relationship between output volatility and economic growth. This is the area where literature is scarce, and it does not reach any conclusion. For instance, Abdelsalam (2020) concludes that there is a positive effect of inflation or output volatility on growth due to the lower opportunity cost of productivity. Harald Badinger (2008), on the other hand, discussed the problem of endogeneity and concluded that there is a negative effect of output volatility on economic growth. Despite the existence of literature on different aspects of the relationship between inflation rate, output, and long-run economic growth, there is limited evidence available on comparing the effects of output and inflation volatilities on economic growth. For policymakers to make informed decisions, the evidence regarding this comparison is of utmost importance. According to the Phillips curve, there is a stable, long-term relationship between inflation and unemployment. It means that high inflation and high unemployment cannot co-exist i.e. there is a trade-off between inflation and unemployment. If inflation is controlled through fiscal and/or monetary policies, then there will be an increase in unemployment. If there is an increase in the aggregate demand then unemployment will reduce but inflation will rise.in this relationship is in line with the Keynesian theory which attributes this negative relationship to the nominal rigidity. The data of 1970, however, did not support the Keynesian hypothesis that there is such a trade-off between inflation and unemployment and also shows a different situation i-e high inflation accompanied by high unemployment, and this type of situation is called stagflation. It was Milton Friedman who challenged Phillips's curve and developed the critique of the original Phillips curve there is no such thing as a tradeoff between inflation and unemployment because of the presence of the natural rate of unemployment which is determined by the real factors in the economy and the long run Phillips curve which is a vertical straight line. According to Friedman Phillips curve is a short transitory relationship and long run the wage earners stick to money illusions and have no expectation that the prices will continue to rise. According to the monetarists, the Phillips curve becomes perfectly inelastic with respect to the rate of change in the price level at the natural rate of unemployment in the long run. According to James Tobin and Keynesian suggest that a Phillips curve relation exists which is quite flat at high levels of unemployment but tends to become vertical as the economy approaches critically low levels of unemployment. So from the whole discussion, it is concluded that in modern macroeconomics there is no tradeoff between inflation and unemployment or inflation and output but the volatility trade exists, in simple words, we conclude that in the Philips curve, we studied that there is a tradeoff between inflation and unemployment mean that if we reduce inflation than unemployment will increase and vice versa and volatility trade mean that if we stable inflation then the output will fluctuate again and again e.g the price of oil, dollar rate, and another increment which come from supply side due to which the economy face inflation. If we take the example of the oil prices nowadays if the inflation is increasing and the state bank commits that it will not let inflation more than 5%, so they will tight the policy due to which the output will decrease, and when the supply condition become better and the price of the oil will decrease then State bank will reverse the policy and output will become better and state bank will do this process again and again to keep the inflation stable and the output will be volatile.
Motivation
The motivation for this study came from recent post-COVID-19 price hikes that resulted from supply chain disruptions and increased demand for commodities due to economic recovery after lifting lockdowns. High inflation rates are observed all over the world but developing countries are especially in the policy dilemma because they also face balance of payments problem and consequent exchange rate risk. So, it is a challenge for their monetary policy to achieve its objectives at minimum cost. If they control inflation more tightly then it will be controlled at the cost of lost output and the latter will become more volatile thereby creating more unemployment. If on the other side, the policy makers take an expansionary policy stance then the inflation rate will further increase but output loss will be lower. In this scenario, policymakers, to make informed policy decisions, need evidence on the comparative costs of output and inflation volatilities.
Problem Statement
The main objective of monetary policy is price stability along with stable output. In the contemporary world, central banks put more weight on inflation due to which the output remains more volatile against shocks that hit the economy. So, in the long run, price stability is achieved at the cost of making output more volatile in the short run. This runs the risk of the very objective of price stability as volatile output, just like inflation, hampers long-run economic growth. Previous literature focuses more on inflation and growth nexus, and the effect of inflation volatility or output volatility on economic growth. But there is no evidence, to the best of our knowledge, on comparative analysis of the effects of inflation and output volatilities on economic growth. Our study hypothesizes that output volatility hampers economic growth even if the effect of inflation volatility is controlled. This needs to estimate the effect of one volatility on economic growth in the presence of the other volatility, which this study aims to do.
Objectives
The main objectives of the paper are:
? To estimate and compare the effects of output and inflation volatilities on economic growth in a panel of countries.
Hypotheses
? Higher inflation volatility reduces economic growth.
? Higher output volatility reduces economic growth.
? Output volatility is harmful to economic growth, even if the effect of inflation volatility is controlled.
Significance of Study
This study is very important in macroeconomics to understand the relationship between economic growth with inflation volatility and output volatility. Many studies have found the relationship between inflation and economic growth but no study, to our knowledge, is available that compares the effects of inflation and output volatilities on economic growth. This study aims at finding, through comparative analysis, which of the two volatilities is more harmful. This will be an important piece of evidence for researchers in the field. The evidence will be especially important for policymakers who have to decide the weight attached to each of these volatilities in the social loss function.
The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 consists of the theoretical framework and empirical methodology. Moreover, it elaborates construction of variables and mentions data sources. Section 3 explains empirical findings while section 4 concludes the study.
Methodology
Theoretical Framework
This study derives its theoretical foundation from neo classical theory of volatility trade-off between inflation and output. This theory is based on aggregate demand and aggregate supply framework and is considered a substitute for the Phillips curve relationship which failed to hold in the 1970s.
The volatility which is explained in the above paragraph is discussed in the model which is as follows.
y_t=?-?r_t+v_t (1)
p_t-p_(t-1)=?y_t+p_t^e-p_(t-1)+?_t (2)
r_t=r+?(?_Pt^e?-0) (3)
p=E_(t-1) (p_t) (4)
Here y means for natural log of real output p means price level; v and u are stochastic shocks and r is the interest rate. Equations 1 and 2 are the aggregate demand function and the supply side of the goods market, which is a standard expectation augmented by Phillips's curve. Equation 3 is the central bank reaction function. Equation 4 defines rational expectation. By simple substitution, equations 5 and 6 are derived:
y_t=-??E_(t-1) (p_t)+v_t (5)
p_t=?y_t=E_(t-1) (p_t)+?_t (6)
By taking expectation and substitution, equations 5 and 6 become:
y_t=v_t
p_t=?y_t+u_t
These reduced-form lead to the following volatility expressions:
var (y)=?_v^2
var (p)=?^2 ?_v^2 +?_u^2
After deriving the output and price variance the revised solutions are:
y_t=(??u_t +v_t)/(1+???)
p_t=?y_t+u_t
The results indicate that demand shocks have a relatively minor impact on real output, whereas supply shocks lead to a more significant effect on real output. Consequently, monetary policy encounters a persistent volatility trade-off, but it does not experience a lasting trade-off between the average real output level and inflation.
Empirical Methodology
We check the effect of output and inflation volatilities on the GDP growth rate. We estimate this relationship in a panel of 68 countries covering the time period 1990 to 2020. Countries are at different stages of development, so single country study does not show the complete picture. Moreover, we use a five-year window to measure standard deviations of output and inflation rate and average values of other variables. Such windows cannot be used in a single country, especially when high-frequency data are unavailable. Our main equation is as follows:
y_it=?_i+?t+?X_it+?Z_it+v_it
Where,
y_it represents the growth rate of real GDP in country i at time period t,
Z_it is the vector of control variable which consists of trade openness, investment to GDP ratio, and labor force growth rate.
X_it is a vector of the main variables of concern - inflation rate and output volatilities.
? (?) are row vectors, which contain coefficients attached to two volatilities (control variables),
?_i and ?t are country and time-specific effects,
and v_it is the error term.
Country-specific effects represent idiosyncratic characteristics of countries that depend on development stage, institutions, size, etc. while time-fixed effects represent global economic conditions. These two effects are very much relevant to our empirical investigation. However, we also use specification tests to identify whether or not the use of a way fixed effect model is appropriate.
The Hausman test is used to find out whether the results of the fixed effect model or the random effect model are more consistent and preferred. Under the null hypothesis of the Hausman test, the random effect estimator is more efficient than the fixed effect estimator though both are consistent; therefore, the RE estimator is superior. The alternate hypothesis states that the FE estimator is consistent, while RE is not, hence the former is preferred. The Hausman test is based on chi-square distribution and is computed as:
H=?[ ?_c- ?_e]?^/ ?[?COV?_c-?COV?_e]?^(-1) [?_C- ?_e]
Where ?_c and ?_e are the coefficient vectors from the consistent and efficient estimator respectively. ?COV?_c and ?COV?_e are the covariance matrix of consistent and efficient estimators respectively.
While the Hausman test is used to choose between FE and RE estimators, the Likelihood ratio test is used to select between different versions of fixed effect mode. i.e. Cross section fixed, time fixed, or two-way FE model. The formula of the LR test is given below:
LR= -2 Ln [ L(?Model?_1 )/L(?Model?_2 ) ]=2 [loglik(?Model?_2 )-loglik (?Model?_1 )]
Where L(?Model?_1 ) and L(?Model?_2 ) represent the likelihood of model 1 and model 2. And loglik(?Model?_2 ) and loglik (?Model?_1 ) show the natural log of model 1 and 2 final likelihood. The likelihood test follows the chi-square distribution.
Construction of Variables:
Inflation Volatility
Inflation volatility means short-term fluctuations in the inflation rate. Volatility is measured by the standard deviation in a 5-year window of inflation rate measured through the GDP deflator.
Economic Growth
Economic growth as the annual percentage growth rate of GDP measured at constant dollars of 2015.
Trade Openness
Trade openness shows the relationship of a country's trade to the outside world and how strong it is. We measure it as the ratio of the sum of exports and imports to GDP.
Investment
Investment is either a net addition to the country's capital stock or it covers the depreciation of existing capital stock. We measure this variable as the ratio of gross fixed capital formation and GDP.
Inflation Rate
Inflation rates refer to decreasing value of currency and increasing prices of goods and services. We measure the inflation rate as the percentage growth rate of the GDP deflator.
Output Volatility
Output volatility represents short-term fluctuations in economic activity. GDP is a trend variable, which can be decomposed into permanent and transitory components. To find short-term fluctuations we remove trends from GDP. We fit the trend in the logarithm of GDP and then estimate the residual, which represents the state of the business cycle. We then measure volatility using the standard deviation of residual in the 5-year window.
Data and Data Source
The study uses secondary data for 68 countries covering time period 1990 to 2020. The choice of countries is consistent with empirical literature on economic growth. In particular, we follow (Feng, 2020) for the selection of countries (Feng, 2020) take 89 countries with a variety of characteristics. We initially considered the same 89 countries but then dropped the countries for which data on our variables are missing for at least five consistent years. The choice of time period is based on the historical turning point of monetary policy focus from economic growth to price stability. We use 5-year windows for standard deviations of the inflation rate and de-trended GDP and average values of all other variables. Data have been taken from World Development Indicators (WDI).
Empirical Findings
The
results of our main regression are given in Table 1. The GDP growth rate has
been regressed on the inflation rate and output volatilities along with three
control variables. We find interesting results. First, inflation volatility has
a negative effect on output growth and the effect is statistically significant
at a 1% significance level. This result is consistent with the existing
empirical literature and is aligned with the economic theory. Second, we find a
negative effect of output volatility on economic growth; this effect too is
statistically significant at a 1% significance level. The result is consistent
with our main hypothesis that output volatility hurts economic growth even if
the negative effect of inflation volatility is controlled. It means that if the
monetary policy stabilizes the inflation rate without putting due weight on
output stabilization, then it cannot provide an enabling environment for
long-run sustained economic growth. The state of the economy, at any particular
point in time, represents business opportunities and future prospects. If
output remains volatile, especially when recessions are more frequent, then
businesses are reluctant to invest in the economy. The lack of investment
further deteriorates the business situation and puts a drag on economic growth.
Third,
we find positive effects of investment to GDP ratio and labor force growth
rates on GDP growth rate; both effects are consistent with economic theory and
empirical literature on growth. The results are also statistically significant
at a 1% level of significance. Fourth, we find the insignificant effect of
trade openness on economic growth. The possible reason for this insignificant
effect can be the time period that we consider in our study. The fast-growing
economies mostly grew at fast rates before 1990 while their openness was also
increasing at that time. During our sample period, newly industrialized
countries were experiencing declining growth rates along with high trade
openness. On the other hand, other emerging economies were experiencing high
growth rates along with increasing trade openness. The combination of these two
different trends makes the effect of trade openness insignificant.
R
square value is almost 60% which shows the goodness of fit of our model. The F
statistics and its probability value show the appropriateness of the overall
model. The results of the Huisman test indicate the appropriateness of using a
fixed effect estimator. The probability value in the Huisman test is less than
0.001 means that the null hypothesis is rejected, so the random effect
estimator is inconsistent. Then we use the likelihood ratio test, which is used
for different versions of the fixed effect model, i.e. whether it should be
cross-section fixed, time fixed, or both. As the probability values of the
three versions of the test are less than 1%, so the flexible model is relevant
for our estimation.
Consistent
with the empirical literature on economic growth we also estimate the same
regression including initial GDP as an additional regressor. This is to capture
the convergence effect. For this specification, we use only the time-fixed
effect as countries' fixed effects are perfectly collinear with initial GDP.
Our results show that there is a negative effect of initial GDP on the growth
rate, which shows the validity of the convergence hypothesis. The results are
statistically significant (table 1). The important take from this specification
is that our main result of negative effects of the inflation rate and output
volatilities on economic growth remains robust to this change in specification.
Table 1
Effect of Inflation and Output
Volatilities On Economic Growth
Specification 1 |
Specification 2 |
|||
Variables |
Coefficient |
SE |
Coefficient |
SE |
Constant |
6.444*** |
1.284 |
11.521*** |
2.014 |
Investment |
16.897*** |
2.686 |
13.655*** |
1.918 |
Labor Growth |
0.532*** |
0.117 |
0.355*** |
0.087 |
Trade Openness |
0.009 |
0.010 |
-0.007* |
0.004 |
Inflation
Volatility |
-0.002*** |
0.000 |
0.002*** |
0.000 |
Output Volatility |
-28.440*** |
3.014 |
-21.870*** |
2.850 |
Initial Output |
-0.203 |
0.067 |
||
R-squared |
0.589 |
0.414 |
||
F-statistics |
6.126 |
25.450 |
||
Prob Value |
0.000 |
0.000 |
||
Hausman Stats |
18.601 |
19.099 |
||
Prob Value |
0.000 |
0.000 |
||
Cross-section F |
2.250 |
|||
Prob Value |
0.000 |
|||
Period F |
25.20 |
19.739 |
||
Prob Value |
0.000 |
0.000 |
||
Cross-Section/Period
F |
3.673 |
|||
Prob Value |
0.000 |
Dependent variable: Real GDP Growth
Rate
Note: ***, **, * represent significance
at 1%, 5%, 10%, respectively. SE represents the standard error of coefficient
estimate
Next, we do a sensitivity analysis to check the robustness
of the results. In the first step, we estimate the same regression but with per
capita GDP growth rate as the dependent variable. In this case, investment to
GDP ratio and trade openness are the two control variables. Results of this
specification (table 2) are consistent with those found in Table 1; the effects
of inflation rate and output volatilities on economic growth are negative and
statistically significant. The effect of control variables also remains stable
to change in specification. The Hausman test and likelihood ratio test also
justify the specification used in the model.
Table 2
Effect of Inflation and Output
Volatilities On Per Worker GDP Growth Rate
Specification 1 |
Specification 2 |
|||
Variables |
Coefficient |
SE |
Coefficient |
SE |
Constant |
5.469*** |
1.284 |
5.041*** |
1.928 |
Investment |
16.346*** |
2.74 |
12.700*** |
2.038 |
Trade Openness |
0.007 |
0.01 |
-0.006 |
0.004 |
Inflation
Volatility |
-0.007*** |
0.00 |
-0.00*** |
0.000 |
Output Volatility |
-27.547** |
3.01 |
-21.87*** |
2.998 |
Initial Output |
-0.20 |
0.07 |
||
R-squared |
0.535 |
0.281 |
||
F-statistics |
4.998 |
15.542 |
||
Prob Value |
0.000 |
0.000 |
||
Hausman Stats |
17.913 |
18.087 |
||
Prob Value |
0.000 |
0.001 |
||
Cross-section F |
2.687 |
|||
Prob Value |
0.000 |
|||
Period F |
22.158 |
13.149 |
||
Prob Value |
0.000 |
0.000 |
||
Cross-Section/Period
F |
3.673 |
|||
Prob Value |
0.00 |
Dependent variable: Real Per Worker
Growth Rate
Note: ***, **, * represent significance
at 1%, 5%, 10%, respectively. SE represents the standard error of coefficient
estimate
In the second step of sensitivity analysis, we estimate our
initial regression but ignore extreme values of inflation rate volatility. In
our sample, the fluctuation of the inflation rate is much higher; the inflation
rate ranges from single digits to five digits. These extreme values may have an
influential effect on our main results. Therefore, we drop extreme values and
re-estimate the regression. The threshold value used to drop observations is
set at 100 for the standard deviation of the inflation rate; only those
countries' years are used for which the standard deviation of the inflation
rate is less than 100. Results in Table 3 show the robustness of our main
results. Both inflation rate and output volatilities have negative effects on
economic growth in specifications with and without initial GDP. The results of
control variables also remain the same as found in the initial regression. This
shows our results are robust to extreme observations.
Table 3
Effect of Inflation and Output
Volatilities On Economic Growth (Inflation Outliers have been dropped)
Specification 1 |
Specification 2 |
|||
Variables |
Coefficient |
SE |
Coefficient |
SE |
Constant |
6.444*** |
1.284 |
11.521*** |
2.014 |
Investment |
16.897*** |
2.686 |
13.655*** |
1.918 |
Labor Growth |
0.532*** |
0.117 |
0.355*** |
0.087 |
Trade Openness |
0.009 |
0.010 |
-0.007* |
0.004 |
Inflation
Volatility |
-0.002*** |
0.000 |
0.002*** |
0.000 |
Output Volatility |
-28.440** |
3.014 |
-21.870** |
2.850 |
Initial Output |
-0.203 |
0.067 |
||
R-squared |
0.589 |
0.414 |
||
F-statistics |
6.126 |
25.450 |
||
Prob Value |
0.000 |
0.000 |
||
Hausman Stats |
18.601 |
19.099 |
||
Prob Value |
0.002 |
0.001 |
||
Cross-section F |
2.245 |
|||
Prob Value |
0.000 |
|||
Period F |
29.199 |
19.739 |
||
Prob Value |
0.000 |
0.000 |
||
Cross-Section/Period
F |
3.615 |
|||
Prob Value |
0.000 |
Dependent variable: Real GDP Growth
Rate
Note: ***, **, * represent significance
at 1%, 5%, 10%, respectively. SE represents the standard error of coefficient
estimate
As a final sensitivity test, we check the effect of output
and inflation rate volatilities on economic growth separately for boom and
recession periods. We categorize a time as a boom (recession) period if the
average value of de-trended GDP is found positive (negative) in 5-year windows.
We construct dummy variables for boom and recession and then find a product of
these dummy variables with the output volatility, which is then used as a
regressors. This specification gives separate estimates of output volatility in
boom and recession. Results in Table 4 show the robustness of our main findings.
Output volatility not only has a negative effect on economic growth in the
presence of inflation volatility, but the effect is also the same in two
different regimes of the business cycle. It means that output volatility is
harmful to economic growth matter the economy is booming or recession. Results
of all other variables are also robust to this change in specification.
Table 4
Effect of Inflation and Output
Volatilities On Economic Growth In Boom And Recession
Specification 1 |
Specification 2 |
|||
Variables |
Coefficient |
SE |
Coefficient |
SE |
Constant |
6.283*** |
1.286 |
11.332*** |
2.010 |
Investment |
17.138*** |
2.686 |
13.833*** |
1.914 |
Labor Growth |
0.541*** |
0.117 |
0.355*** |
0.087 |
Trade Openness |
0.008 |
0.010 |
-0.007* |
0.004 |
Inflation
Volatility |
-0.002*** |
0.000 |
-0.002*** |
0.000 |
Output Volatility
positive |
-28.415*** |
3.008 |
-21.980** |
2.840 |
Output Volatility
negative |
-27.795** |
3.038 |
-21.184 |
2.862 |
Initial Output |
-0.201 |
0.067 |
||
R-squared |
0.591 |
0.420 |
||
F-statistics |
6.099 |
23.800 |
||
Prob Value |
0.000 |
0.000 |
||
Hausman Stats |
19.563 |
20.257 |
||
Prob Value |
0.000 |
0.020 |
||
Cross-section F |
2.218 |
|||
Prob Value |
0.000 |
|||
Period F |
24.391 |
19.209 |
||
Prob Value |
0.000 |
0.000 |
||
Cross-Section/Period
F |
3.544 |
|||
Prob Value |
0.000 |
Dependent variable: Real GDP Growth
Rate
Note: ***, **, * represent significance
at 1%, 5%, 10%, respectively. SE represents the standard error of coefficient
estimate
As mentioned in the introduction of this section, we also
estimate the relationship between the growth rate and average values of the
inflation rate and de-trended GDP. This is consistent with somewhat old
empirical literature in the framework of the Phillips curve that shows the
trade-off between average values of inflation rate and economic activity.
Results in Table 5 show that the inflation rate and de-trended GDP both have a
negative effect on the GDP growth rate. This shows that not only inflation rate
volatility is harmful to economic growth the higher values of the inflation
rate do the same. The same is the case with business cycle fluctuations; higher
fluctuations lead to less output growth. All other results are the same as
those found in the main regression. Moreover, the results of the inflation
rate, business cycle fluctuation, and control variables remain the same in
specifications with and without initial GDP.
Table 5
Effect of Inflation and Output on
Economic Growth
Specification 1 |
Specification 2 |
|||
Variables |
Coefficient |
SE |
Coefficient |
SE |
Constant |
-2.691*** |
0.947 |
2.868*** |
1.774 |
Investment |
20.185*** |
2.895 |
14.351*** |
2.012 |
Labor Growth |
0.622*** |
0.126 |
0.454*** |
0.09 |
Trade Openness |
0.005 |
0.011 |
-0.009* |
0.090 |
Average Inflation |
0.009*** |
0.001 |
0.007*** |
0.001 |
B.Cycle |
-1.609*** |
1.836 |
-1.151*** |
1.908 |
Initial Output |
-0.122 |
0.069 |
||
R-squared |
0.520 |
0.360 |
||
F-statistics |
4.638 |
20.226 |
||
Prob Value |
0.000 |
0.000 |
||
Hausman Stats |
38.900 |
26.511 |
||
Prob Value |
0.000 |
0.000 |
||
Cross-section F |
1.692 |
|||
Prob Value |
0.001 |
|||
Period F |
6.768 |
8.086 |
||
Prob Value |
0.000 |
0.000 |
||
Cross-Section/Period
F |
2.178 |
|||
Prob Value |
0.000 |
Dependent variable: Real GDP Growth
Rate
Note: ***, **, * represent significance
at 1%, 5%, 10%, respectively. SE represents the standard error of coefficient
estimate
In the final step, we estimate separate effects of business
cycle fluctuations on economic growth in boom and recession. All other
variables are the same as those in the last specification. As shown in Table 6,
our main results are also robust to this change in specification. Inflation
rate and business cycle fluctuations have negative effects on economic growth.
More importantly, we find that the negative effects of the business cycle are
more pronounced in a recession as compared to that in a boom. This shows that
though the business cycle fluctuations are harmful to economic growth in both
regimes the effect is much higher in recessions. This shows the importance of
output stabilization along with price stability and policy response to output
fluctuations is much more needed in recessions.
Table 6
Effect of Inflation and Output on
Economic Growth In Boom And Recession
Specification 1 |
Specification 2 |
|||
Variables |
Coefficient |
SE |
Coefficient |
SE |
Constant |
-2.715*** |
0.957 |
2.642*** |
1.813 |
Investment |
20.157** |
2.904 |
14.338*** |
2.014 |
Labor Growth |
0.625*** |
0.127 |
0.466*** |
0.092 |
Trade Openness |
0.005 |
0.011 |
-0.009* |
0.004 |
Inflation |
-0.009*** |
0.001 |
0.007*** |
0.001 |
B.cycle positive |
-0.867 |
4.350 |
0.690 |
3.569 |
B. cycle negative |
-2.146 |
3.392 |
-2.433 |
2.837 |
|
|
|
|
|
Initial Output |
-0.116 |
0.070 |
||
R-squared |
0.520 |
0.360 |
||
F-statistics |
4.566 |
18.542 |
||
Prob Value |
0.000 |
0.000 |
||
Hausman Stats |
23.717 |
25.759 |
||
Prob Value |
0.000 |
0.000 |
||
Cross-section F |
1.675 |
|||
Prob Value |
0.001 |
|||
Period F |
6.612 |
7.798 |
||
Prob Value |
0.000 |
0.000 |
||
Cross-Section/Period
F |
2.138 |
|||
Prob Value |
0.000 |
Dependent variable:
Real GDP Growth Rate
Note: ***, **, * represent significance at 1%, 5%, 10%, respectively. SE represents the standard error of coefficient estimate
Conclusion
According to previous studies, a lot of research has been done on the relationship between inflation and growth, the effect of inflation volatility on economic growth, and the effect of output volatility on growth but no study has estimated the effect of one volatility controlling the effect of the other. In practice, central banks in the modern world put more weight on inflation volatility due to which the output becomes more volatile. We estimate growth regression in a panel of 68 countries and a time span of 190 to 2020 with both inflation rate and output volatilities as regressors. Our results show that both volatilities are harmful to economic growth. The negative effect of output volatility on economic growth is observed even after controlling the effect of inflation rate volatility. This result is robust to different specifications of the empirical model and drops extreme observations.
Our results have clear policy implications. Central banks of developing countries should maintain a balance between output stabilization and price stability. If they put more weight on price stability then output remains volatile, especially against supply shocks. Thus, price stability that is achieved at the cost of output volatility does not remain fruitful for long-term growth.
Appendix
Country Name |
S.No |
Country Name |
|
1 |
Albania |
35 |
Sri Lanka |
2 |
Armenia |
36 |
Madagascar |
3 |
Azerbaijan |
37 |
Mexico |
4 |
Burundi |
38 |
Mali |
5 |
Benin |
39 |
Mongolia |
6 |
Burkina Faso |
40 |
Malaysia |
7 |
Bangladesh |
41 |
Namibia |
8 |
Bulgaria |
42 |
Niger |
9 |
Brazil |
43 |
Nicaragua |
10 |
Botswana |
44 |
Nepal |
11 |
Central African
Republic |
45 |
Oman |
12 |
Cote d'lvoire |
46 |
Pakistan |
13 |
Cameroon |
47 |
Panama |
14 |
Congo |
48 |
Peru |
15 |
Colombia |
49 |
Philippines |
16 |
Dominican Republic |
50 |
Paraguay |
17 |
Ecuador |
51 |
Russian Federation |
18 |
Egypt |
52 |
Rwanda |
19 |
Gabon |
53 |
Sudan |
20 |
United Kingdom |
54 |
Senegal |
21 |
Ghana |
55 |
El Salvador |
22 |
Guinea |
56 |
Swaziland |
23 |
Gambia |
57 |
Chad |
24 |
Guinea- Bissau |
58 |
Togo |
25 |
Guatemala |
59 |
Thailand |
26 |
Honduras |
60 |
Tunisia |
27 |
India |
61 |
Turkey |
28 |
Iran |
62 |
Tanzania, |
29 |
Jamaica |
63 |
Uganda |
30 |
Jordan |
64 |
Ukraine |
31 |
Japan |
65 |
Uruguay |
32 |
Kazakhstan |
66 |
United States |
33 |
Kenya |
67 |
South Africa |
34 |
Lebanon |
68 |
Zimbabwe |
References
-
Abdelsalam, M. a. M. (2020). Oil price fluctuations and economic growth: the case of MENA countries. Review of Economics and Political Science, 8(5), 353–379. https://doi.org/10.1108/reps-12-2019-0162
- Badinger, H. (2008). Fiscal rules, discretionary fiscal policy, and macroeconomic stability: an empirical assessment for OECD countries. Applied Economics, 41(7), 829–847. https://doi.org/10.1080/00036840701367556
- Barro, R. J. (1996). Democracy and Growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 1(1), 1–27. http://www.jstor.org/stable/40215879
- Barro, R. J. (1995). Inflation and economic growth (NBER Working Paper No. 5326). National Bureau of Economic Research. https://www.nber.org/system/files/working_papers/w5326/w5326.pdf
- Fisher, R. J. (1993). Social desirability bias and the validity of indirect questioning. Journal of Consumer Research, 20(2), 303. https://doi.org/10.1086/209351
- Friedman, M. (1977). Nobel Lecture: Inflation and Unemployment. Journal of Political Economy, 85(3), 451–472. https://doi.org/10.1086/260579
- Guo, M., & Lim, E. (2024). Does inflation targeting matter for price stability? International Review of Economics & Finance, 91, 1015–1032. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2024.01.035
- Judson, R., & Orphanides, A. (1999). Inflation, volatility, and growth. international Finance, 2(1), 117-138.
- Motley, B. (1994). Growth and inflation: A cross-country study (No. 395). Center for Economic Policy Research, Stanford University.
- Zhang, R., Zhao, W., & Wang, Y. (2023). Is there a relationship between economic growth and natural resource commodity price volatility? Evidence from China. Resources Policy, 88, 104391. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resourpol.2023.104391
-
Abdelsalam, M. a. M. (2020). Oil price fluctuations and economic growth: the case of MENA countries. Review of Economics and Political Science, 8(5), 353–379. https://doi.org/10.1108/reps-12-2019-0162
- Badinger, H. (2008). Fiscal rules, discretionary fiscal policy, and macroeconomic stability: an empirical assessment for OECD countries. Applied Economics, 41(7), 829–847. https://doi.org/10.1080/00036840701367556
- Barro, R. J. (1996). Democracy and Growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 1(1), 1–27. http://www.jstor.org/stable/40215879
- Barro, R. J. (1995). Inflation and economic growth (NBER Working Paper No. 5326). National Bureau of Economic Research. https://www.nber.org/system/files/working_papers/w5326/w5326.pdf
- Fisher, R. J. (1993). Social desirability bias and the validity of indirect questioning. Journal of Consumer Research, 20(2), 303. https://doi.org/10.1086/209351
- Friedman, M. (1977). Nobel Lecture: Inflation and Unemployment. Journal of Political Economy, 85(3), 451–472. https://doi.org/10.1086/260579
- Guo, M., & Lim, E. (2024). Does inflation targeting matter for price stability? International Review of Economics & Finance, 91, 1015–1032. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2024.01.035
- Judson, R., & Orphanides, A. (1999). Inflation, volatility, and growth. international Finance, 2(1), 117-138.
- Motley, B. (1994). Growth and inflation: A cross-country study (No. 395). Center for Economic Policy Research, Stanford University.
- Zhang, R., Zhao, W., & Wang, Y. (2023). Is there a relationship between economic growth and natural resource commodity price volatility? Evidence from China. Resources Policy, 88, 104391. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resourpol.2023.104391
Cite this article
-
APA : Iqbal, N., Rehman, A., & Malik, W. S. (2024). A Comparative Analysis of the Effects of Price Instability and Output Volatility on Economic Growth. Global Management Sciences Review, IX(III), 131-142. https://doi.org/10.31703/gmsr.2024(IX-III).11
-
CHICAGO : Iqbal, Nadeem, Aisha Rehman, and Wasim Shahid Malik. 2024. "A Comparative Analysis of the Effects of Price Instability and Output Volatility on Economic Growth." Global Management Sciences Review, IX (III): 131-142 doi: 10.31703/gmsr.2024(IX-III).11
-
HARVARD : IQBAL, N., REHMAN, A. & MALIK, W. S. 2024. A Comparative Analysis of the Effects of Price Instability and Output Volatility on Economic Growth. Global Management Sciences Review, IX, 131-142.
-
MHRA : Iqbal, Nadeem, Aisha Rehman, and Wasim Shahid Malik. 2024. "A Comparative Analysis of the Effects of Price Instability and Output Volatility on Economic Growth." Global Management Sciences Review, IX: 131-142
-
MLA : Iqbal, Nadeem, Aisha Rehman, and Wasim Shahid Malik. "A Comparative Analysis of the Effects of Price Instability and Output Volatility on Economic Growth." Global Management Sciences Review, IX.III (2024): 131-142 Print.
-
OXFORD : Iqbal, Nadeem, Rehman, Aisha, and Malik, Wasim Shahid (2024), "A Comparative Analysis of the Effects of Price Instability and Output Volatility on Economic Growth", Global Management Sciences Review, IX (III), 131-142
-
TURABIAN : Iqbal, Nadeem, Aisha Rehman, and Wasim Shahid Malik. "A Comparative Analysis of the Effects of Price Instability and Output Volatility on Economic Growth." Global Management Sciences Review IX, no. III (2024): 131-142. https://doi.org/10.31703/gmsr.2024(IX-III).11